Is vaccination good economics as well as good politics?
Vaccinating children is obviously good politics, demonstrating what can be achieved with aid. There was great celebration when the Global Alliance for Vaccines and Immunisation (GAVI) raised over $US 4 bn at its pledging conference in London, back in June. David Cameron even received a standing ovation for pledging some $US.1.3bn. 250 million children will be vaccinated. 100 million lives will be saved. Fantastic.
The immediate economics is also highly positive. Look at the 2008 summary, below, of health ‘best-buys’ by the Disease Control Priorities Project. Vaccinating children against major childhood diseases comes top of the list. Again, a fantastic investment.
- Vaccinate children against major childhood diseases, including tuberculosis, diphtheria, whooping cough, tetanus, polio, and measles (the traditional expanded program of immunization).
- Monitor children’s health to prevent or, if necessary, treat childhood pneumonia, diarrhea, and malaria.
- Tax tobacco products to increase consumers’ costs by at least one-third and reduce cases of cardiovascular disease, cancer, and respiratory disease (see Box 1 on page 4).
- Prevent the spread of HIV through a coordinated approach that includes: promoting 100 percent condom use among populations at high risk of infection; treating other sexually transmitted infections; providing antiretroviral medications to pregnant women; and offering voluntary HIV counseling and testing.
- Give children and pregnant women essental nutrients, including vitamin A, iron, and iodine, to prevent maternal anemia, infant deaths, and longterm health problems.
- Provide insecticide-treated bed nets, household spraying of insecticides, and preventive treatment for pregnant women to drastically reduce malaria in areas where it is endemic.
- Enforce traffic regulations and install speed bumps at dangerous intersections to reduce traffic-related injuries.
- Treat tuberculosis patients with short- course chemotherapy to cure infected people and prevent new infections (see Box 2 on page 5).
- Teach mothers and train birth attendants to keep newborns warm and clean to reduce illness and death.
- Promote the use of aspirin and other inexpensive drugs to prevent and treat heart attack and stroke.
Hang on a minute, though. The major pledges to GAVI were not for the traditional ‘expanded programme of immunization’ (EPI), but mainly for new vaccines, especially against rotavirus and pneumococcal infection. The press release and other coverage confirms that this is the case. The figure below shows that new vaccines are the biggest growth areas. Are the economics then as clear?
What led me to ask this question was the juxtaposition of the figure raised at the London conference, $US 4.3 bn, with the number of children to be vaccinated, 250m, and the number of lives to be saved, 4 m. Obviously, it is wonderful to save 4 million young lives, but an immediate mental calculation, dividing $4.3 bn by 4 m, told me that each life saved was going to cost over $US 1000. That seemed a lot, especially given what we know about health budgets in developing countries (less than $US 100 per capita for the poorest 100 countries in the world, even in purchasing power parity dollars) and about the extremely low cost of some other interventions – for example, micronutrient supplementation. Every investment has an opportunity cost. Could even more lives have been saved by raising the same amount of money for nutrition?
The GAVI event also triggered a memory – of being invited to a lunch in London a few years ago, when I was Director of ODI, the purpose of which was for a pharmaceutical company to discuss with development people the following issue: ‘at great cost to ourselves, we have invented some new vaccines, including against rotavirus, and we want to persuade donors to pay for them; they are quite expensive; how do we do that?’.
I remember making the argument that we development specialists believed very strongly in rational public expenditure allocation, that we helped to design medium term expenditure frameworks, that we opposed vertical programmes that parachuted money into health ministries with no regard for country ownership, national priorities or the need to build health systems; and that therefore the logical thing for the pharmaceutical companies to do was to make a careful argument for cost-effectiveness, based on sector programmes at health ministry level, within overall national public expenditure ceilings.
You can see that I was reflecting faithfully, and with conviction, I might say, the conventional wisdom of ODI’s public expenditure specialists. I also had in mind the famous case of the Uganda health ministry back in 2002, being offered more money from the Global Fund for HIV/AIDSHuman Immuno-Deficiency Virus/Aquired Immuneo-Deficiency Syndrome than the whole health budget of the country, and the horrified reaction of the Ministry of Finance at the distortion this implied to overall spending patterns.
My thinking then was consistent with scepticism about what later I have come to call Results 1.0, the view that maintaining political support for aid requires such a strong focus on results that ‘simple’ interventions, like vaccination, trump more complex and equally important ones like support to the institutions required for better governance. As readers of a previous contribution will know, I think Andrew Mitchell is managing this conundrum well, with a subtle agenda I have called Results 2.0.
The interesting part of this story, though, is the reaction of the pharmaceutical company representatives, senior people all, who looked at me as though I was both deranged and naïve beyond belief. That, their expressions said, is not how it works.
You can understand then, my interest being awoken, on finding, only a few years later, that the vertical fund created to fund vaccination was making a major commitment to new vaccines, at what seemed a high cost per life saved. Was this the triumph of politics over economics? Or had the economics changed?
I raised these questions at an ODI/IDS meeting on results, and again at a World Bank seminar in London in September. Some interesting points have come up.
First, of course, the cost per life saved is a crude way to think about the economics, and it is more accurate to use Disability-Adjusted Life Years (DALYS), appropriately valued and discounted.
Second, a DALY perspective confirms that traditional EPI vaccination is highly cost-effective, at less than $US 10 per DALY averted.
Third, the new vaccines are indeed much more expensive, though coming down in price, which makes a literature review and comparative analysis quite complicated. The GAVI page on cost-effectiveness makes statements about cost-effectiveness, but does not give numbers. See: http://www.gavialliance.org/about/value/cost-effective/. The Disease Control Priority Project cites rotavirus is cited as a “high-cost intervention” in both South Asia ($US 500-7000 per DALY averted) and SSASub-Saharan Africa ( $US 500-1700). There are no data for pneumococcal vaccinations, as far as I can see. However, there are plenty of refs on the web to DALYs and pneumococcal vaccine. The Lancet paper cited by GAVI says $US 100 per DALY averted. A 2011 paper comparing different models has figures from $US 767 - $US 4000 (see http://www.biomedcentral.com/1741-7015/9/53).
Fourth, micronutrient supplementation is not the only nutrition intervention to score highly in comparative tests of cost-effectiveness. Work for the Copenhagen Consensus shows many nutrition interventions with cost per DALY saved below $US 20, or in the range $US 20-100. See http://thousanddays.org/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/Copenhagen-Consensus-2008-summary.pdf.
Fifth, there are many other cost-effective investments available to save lives and reduce poverty – including insecticide-impregnated bednets, measures to provide clean water and better sanitation, improved stoves to reduce smoke inhalation, and many others. I brought some lists together when writing in 2008 about the need to move from risk frameworks to opportunities frameworks.
However . . .
Sixth, it is not surprising that new vaccines are more expensive than well-established ones, since R and D costs have to be amortised. Eventually, the cost of new vaccines will come down and be competitive. Owen Barder, for example, has argued that the extra initial price is worth paying to cover the costs of development (and investment in production) for new vaccines, provided that in the long run prices fall down to the social marginal cost. That’s interesting and sounds like a standard cost-benefit problem. We’re comparing two investments, one of which (new vaccines) is expensive now but will be cheaper later, the other of which is relatively cheap now and in the future. Which we choose depends on the relative prices now and later, and on the discount rate. Without carrying out detailed calculations, Figure 1 below illustrates the issue. It shows the actual costs over a 50-year period, with a nutrition intervention constant in price at $US 20 per DALY, and two options for vaccination, the first at $US 100, declining by 10% a year, the second with the same initial cost, declining at 5% a year. The vaccinations are eventually cheaper. However, if a discount rate of 10% is applied, the nutrition intervention still comes out top, because the initial cost is so much lower. Remember, these numbers are hyothetical.
Figure 1
What do I conclude from all this? Well, the politicians may think the politics is complicated, but, speaking as an economist, it seems to me that the economics is pretty complicated too. An awful lot depends on which method is used to calculate cost-effectiveness, and on the specific valuations and discount rates applied. There is no excuse, however, for advisers not to carry out the analysis and present ministers with costed options.
What should ministers then do? Logically, they should start at the top and work down. Practically, they will want to think about the politics as well as the economics, and about feasibility and adminsitrative simplicity. Probably they will find good reasons to invest in vaccines, both old and `` They will also find many good reasons to invest in other interventions to save the lives of poor children. Nutrition will be high on the list.
Comments
This point, however, is not news but rather the everyday meat & potatoes of global health.
In fact, a number of key points argue that introducing new vaccines is smarter economics than politics. Let’s start with the economics. First, even at the prices that new vaccines are available right now,most studies demonstrate they provide good value for money in terms of their cost-effectiven ess. Second, those countries who are eligible for new vaccine support through the GAVI Alliance obtain the vaccines for at least a 5 year period at steeply discounted prices and with a small co-payment that makes the vaccinations cost-savings in most if not all cases. Indeed, over a 10 year period, when the combined price of the vaccines and the cost of the co-payment are merged, the economics of the program are sound.
Lastly on the economics, Simon Maxwell offers a skewed hypothetical analysis of the costs and benefits in his figure. By discounting the costs of the program but not the benefits, he skews the analysis. A more accurate analysis would discount both the benefits and costs and gives a very different picture of the trade-offs.
Vaccines are not generally good politics, even though we would argue that they should be. Vaccines tend to save the lives of young babies born in rural areas who have little if any voice in the politics of setting national priorities. As countless urban hospital projects with dialysis and cancer treatment centers attest, the politics ofhealth in countries tends to favor treatment of chronic diseases of adults not prevention of deaths in rural babies.
More attention should be paid to the issues of vaccine economics and financing in the years ahead. And as this blog post shows, they should consider all the evidence, not just the ones that fit a stated position, and be based on rigorous evaluations.
-Orin Levine, together with Anushua Sinha,
'
The cost-effectiven ess of the new vaccines supported by GAVI have been scrutinised in several recent peer-reviewed research papers, and it is the new vaccines Mr Maxwell was concerned about in the blog (he accepted the “old” EPI vaccines are good value).
(a)Tasslimi et al. (International Health, November 2011) model the cost-effectiven ess of the Pneumococcal Conjugate Vaccine (PCV) in the 72 GAVI-eligible countries, and find it highly cost-effective in all but 3 countries using cautious modelling assumptions and PCV7. Taking into account the emergence of new versions (PCV10 and PCV13) cost-effectiven ess is higher. For example, the mean cost per DALY averted using PCV13 is calculated to be $US 77. These costs per DALY averted are considerably lower for the countries with the poorest health situation; for example for those 16 countries with Under-five mortality above 150, these costs across the range of PCV7, PCV10 and PCV13 is $US 37-65.
(b)Kim et al. (BMC Infectious Diseases, 2011) reviews the health and other consequences of introducing HPV and rotavirus in GAVI-eligible countries, finding also that under various modelling assumptions, a high cost-effectiven ess in terms of incremental cost per DALY averted, at levels below the GDP per capita for each country, and similar order of magnitude as for PCV.
One difficulty with vaccine cost-effectiven ess analysis is that the price of the vaccine is a crucial variable affecting the calculations; in this case, it makes the cost-effectiven ess calculations cautious. One feature of a new technology is that R&D expenditure has to be made upfront, and vaccines reproduction costs will fall to very small levels once first developed. A result is that focusing attention on the initial costs is misleading. In any case, life time costs matter, not initial costs. This point was made by the Minister of State in his oral evidence (and is one which Mr Maxwell clearly acknowledges in the blog).
The need for initial large investment also implies that (marginal) costs and prices will face substantial downward pressure. Without GAVI, some of these vaccines would not be developed or reach developing countries much slower. It makes GAVI well placed to use its influence to ensure that prices come down after development. For example, at the June 2011 GAVI replenishment, GSK announced a significant reduction in the price of its rotavirus vaccine.
12. Another issue that vaccine cost-effectiven ess depends on the epidemiology of a disease locally; global comparisons make little sense. To take an extreme example just for illustrative purposes, if there was a highly effective malaria vaccine at a moderate price it would probably be highly cost-effective in areas of Africa where the average child gets four to five attacks of malaria a year, but not be in any way cost-effective in Turkey, where most children never get malaria. GAVI cost-effectiven ess analysis takes this into account and advice is tailored locally; not every vaccine is appropriate everywhere. In the papers cited above, cost-effectiven ess is calculated country-by-country.
A current example is polio. The current cost per case averted from the polio eradication attempt is of course huge- because polio is almost eradicated and there are very few cases. The cost of stopping vaccination on this basis would of course also be massive, in both human and financial terms as eradication would fail and polio would sweep back (ironically making the cost-effectiven ess of the vaccine, in the way Mr. Maxwell calculates it, look much more attractive). Comparing this to nutrition clearly misses the point of both.
Additionally there is a herd effect for vaccination once it reaches a substantial proportion of the population- the fact that 80% of children are protected reduces the risk for the other 20%. Proper modelling needs to take this into account. For most other interventions (including nutrition) this is not so.'
publications.parliament.uk/... /...
'Cost Effectiveness of New Vaccines
The Committee were particularly interested in the cost effectiveness of the new Rotavirus and Pneumococcus vaccines that GAVI is introducing compared to the cost of Vitamin A and sanitation.
Below are two recent articles on the cost effectiveness of pneumococcal (Tasslimi et al 2011) and rotavirus (Atherly et al2009) vaccines.
Atherly et al (2009) estimates a $7 cost (declining over time) per course of Rotavirus Vaccine and found that the cumulative (over the period 2007–25) cost of averting a DALY is $43. The cost per DALY averted decreases over time, from a high of US$450 per DALY averted in the first year to a sustained low of $30 per DALY during 2017–25, with an overall figure of $43 per DALY averted during 2008–25. The $5 per course price announced this year by GSK is likely to improve the cost-effectiven ess further.
Tasslimi et al found that compared to no vaccination, the pooled cost-effectiven ess ratio for the PCV-13 Pneumococcal Vaccine was $77–$105 per DALY averted in GAVI-eligible countries. Tasslimi et al projected the cost of the vaccine over a 10 year period, starting from $21.57 per course ending at $12.90 per course. We suspect this estimation to be conservative, as the current GAVI financials report a price per course of $10.50.
Costs per DALY averted of Vitamin A supplements are $6–12 (DCPP) and for Sanitation vary according to interventions and context: $11–270 (DCPP).
The Committee can therefore see that the costs of these new vaccines is falling, compared to the earlier estimates cited by Maxwell. They are much lower than the upper end of the range of cost per DALY for sanitation, and a little higher than the cost per DALY for Vitamin A supplements.
Bringing Down the Prices of New Vaccines
The Committee can see that the price of the new Rotavirus and Pneumococcus vaccines are falling, not least because of the demand crated by GAVI. However, they are not as low as the traditional EPI (expanded program of immunization) vaccines for tuberculosis, diphtheria, whooping cough, tetanus, polio, and measles.
GAVI’s mandate is to ensure countries provide the traditional expanded program of immunization but mainly to introduce new vaccines. GAVI’s model is to gradually move the cost of all vaccines in a sustainable way into government’s own health budgets. As a result, new vaccines are a large share of GAVI’s total budget. The table below is the latest Financial Forecast Update (2011–15) approved by the GAVI Board in July 2011. It shows that Rotavirus and Pneumococcus vaccines represent 56% of GAVI’s vaccine programmes.
Approved/Endors ed Extensions Balance of Demand Total
Programmes
Penta $1,164 $215 $160 $1,539
Pneumo 1,080 586 769 $2,435
Rota 103 302 $404
Other vaccines 198 5 454 $657
Total vaccine programmes $2,544 $806 $1,684 $5,035 82%
Cash-based programmes 379 729 $1,108 18%
Total programmes $2,924 $806 $2,413 $6,143 100%
Business plan 252 436 $689
Total expenditures $3,176 $1,243 $2,413 $6,832
But as the articles show, we can expect the cost of these new vaccines to fall after 2015. This will allow more children to be vaccinated and further new vaccines to be introduced.
GAVI’s ability to pool procurement helps it to bring down the costs of vaccines. DFID, the Gates Foundation and others are working with GAVI and UNICEF to develop and implement innovative procurement strategies to help secure long-term supply and further reduce prices for new vaccines.
In addition, the Gates Foundation and others are making a number of investments which are bringing down the costs of vaccination. The foundation has made several investments in developing world manufacturers to increase the supplier base and spur competition. We provide R&D financial and technical support to accelerate the development of vaccines in exchange for the establishment of ceiling prices to make vaccines affordable for GAVI-eligible countries and ensure value for money for donors.
Setting Priorities
The Gates Foundation firmly believes in prioritising scarce development resources by supporting the most cost effective interventions. Cost per DALY averted is a major consideration in our decisions about the health interventions we invest in, and for which we advocate. The Gates Foundation provided support for the Disease Control Priorities Project cited by Maxwell, in order to provide the evidence on “best health buys” in developing countries, based on studies that have identified successful and cost-effective interventions. We are supporting a new edition of the DCPP work.
However, as the DCPP says, evidence about what works is only a starting point. As Maxwell also says, “Logically, [Ministers] should start at the top and work down. Practically, they will want to think about the politics as well as the economics, and about feasibility and administrative simplicity. Probably they will find good reasons to invest in vaccines, both old and new. They will also find many good reasons to invest in other interventions to save the lives of poor children.”
Critically, the Gates Foundation also looks at disease burden. As the Committee can see in the table above, an aspirin to prevent heart disease is similar to the cost of managing childhood illnesses, including diarrhoea and vitamin A deficiency. But the burden of childhood illnesses is much higher. And so we focus our efforts on the diseases with the highest burden, especially on children.
It is also important to take marginal cost effectiveness into account. What is the value of each additional dollar spent on a particular health intervention? This must take account of what is already going on. Although traditional Childhood Immunization and Vitamin A supplements are highly cost effective, it would not make sense to allocate all ODA (or government health budgets) to these interventions. It would be appropriate to allocate sufficient finance to these interventions before continuing down the table of best buys. This explains why, as Jeff Raikes told the Committee, we invest heavily in Nutrition and Sanitation as well as (new and old) vaccines. And all development organisations must also take account of their own comparative advantage.
By combining all these factors, we come to our decision to invest substantially in new Rotavirus and Pneumococcus vaccines. By creating the market, the price for these vaccines has fallen over time to well within the range of health best buys. Pneumonia and Diarrheal Diseases account for 33% of (under five) childhood deaths. And, as we work down the cost effectiveness league table, interventions to prevent and treat pneumonia and diarrheal diseases are much higher than many alternative interventions, even if they are not yet at the very top.
publications.parliament.uk/... /...